fbpx

ECONOMY

ECONOMY

How Will Bitcoin Move?

Read this article on other language
Download article
image_pdf
image_pdf

Part 1 – Introduction, Literature Review and Data Description 

This first part of this article consists of introductory information about Bitcoin, literature review, data descriptions and potential models to determine what we predict about Bitcoin’s volatility (such as GARCH modeling for example) and value based on past data. Further parts will mainly be data analysis of the cryptocurrency, and thus predictions of future prices, returns or volatility. The creators of Bitcoin set up the digital currency in an effort to eliminate the need for trusted third parties to complete digital financial transactions. We here represent the ideas of Satoshi Nakamoto, the pseudonymous identity of the person/s behind Bitcoin, as presented in their white paper.

Trading online, Nakamoto asserts, has come to rely almost exclusively on financial institutions serving as trusted third parties to process electronic payments. While the system works well enough for most transactions, it still suffers from the inherent weaknesses of the trust-based model. Completely non-reversible transactions are not possible since financial institutions cannot avoid mediating disputes. The cost of mediation increases transaction costs, limiting the minimum practical transaction size and cutting off the possibility for small casual transactions, and thus there is a broader cost in the loss of ability to make non-reversible payments for non-reversible services. With the possibility of reversal, the need for trust spreads. Merchants must be wary of their customers, hassling them for more information than they would otherwise need. A certain percentage of fraud is accepted as unavoidable. These costs and payment uncertainties are avoided in person through the use of physical currency, but no mechanism yet exists, asserted Nakamoto in 2008, to make payments over a communications channel without a trusted party. What cryptocurrencies require is an electronic payment system based on cryptographic proof instead of trust, allowing any two willing parties to transact directly with each other without the need for a trusted third party. Transactions that are computationally impractical to reverse would protect sellers from fraud, and routine escrow mechanisms could easily be implemented to protect buyers (Nakamoto 2008).

Our modern economy, Nakamoto continues, relies heavily on digital means of payments. Trade in the form of e-commerce, for example, necessitates the usage of digital tokens. In a digital currency system, the means of payment is simply a string of bits. This poses a problem, as these strings of bits, like any other digital record, can easily be copied and re-used for payment. Essentially, a digital token can be counterfeited by using it twice; this is the so-called double-spending problem. Traditionally, this problem has been overcome by relying on a trusted third-party who manages for a fee a centralized ledger and transfers balances by crediting and debiting buyers and sellers’ accounts. This third-party is often the issuer of the digital currency itself, one prominent example being PayPal, and the value of the currency derives from the fact that users trust the third-party to prohibit double-spending. Cryptocurrencies such as Bitcoin go a step further and remove the need for a trusted third-party. Instead, the creators of Bitcoin sought to address this problem by relying on a decentralized network of (possibly anonymous) validators to maintain and update copies of the ledger.

This necessitates that consensus between the validators is maintained about the correct record of transactions so that the users can be sure to receive and keep ownership of balances. But such a consensus ultimately requires that users do not double-spend the currency and that users can trust the validators to accurately update the ledger. How do cryptocurrencies such as Bitcoin tackle these challenges? Trust in the currency is based on a blockchain which ensures the distributed verification, updating and storage of the record of transaction histories. This is done by forming a blockchain. A block is a set of transactions that have been conducted between the users of the cryptocurrency. A chain is created from these blocks containing the history of past transactions that allows one to create a ledger where one can publicly verify the amount of balances or currency a user owns. Hence, a blockchain is like a book containing the ledger of all past transactions with a block being a new page recording all the current transactions.

From January 2017 through December, Bitcoin increased in value by 1270%, and the total cryptocurrency trading volume passed USD 5 billion a day. Interest from the mainstream media, regulators, the public and financial markets accelerated so much that some call this period Bitcoin’s “IPO moment.” During 2017, Bitcoin gained more focus from institutional money, hedge funds, and public funds. Its success culminated with the approval and introduction of Bitcoin derivatives.

Several authors have attempted to describe Bitcoin as a currency, stock, or asset. Yermack (2013) argues that Bitcoin appears to behave more similarly to a speculative store of value rather than a currency. Dwyer (2015), on the other hand, describes Bitcoin as an electronic currency that can be used to trade and can be stored in a personal balance sheet. Dwyer’s argument is supported by Polasik (2015), who adds that Bitcoin can operate as a medium of exchange alongside other payment technologies.

An increasing number of researchers have focused on the existence of a fundamental value of Bitcoin, and some have studied whether or not it is a bubble. Garcia (2014) finds that Bitcoin is a financial bubble because of the difference between the exchange rate and fundamental value of Bitcoin. He argues for a fundamental value given the cost of mining. Similarly, Hayes (2015, 2018) proposed a specific cost of production model for valuating Bitcoin. Additionally, Cheah and Fry (2015) conclude that Bitcoin is a speculative bubble and that the fundamental value of Bitcoin is zero.

Unlike earlier studies, Corbet (2017) found that there is no clear evidence of a bubble in Bitcoin. While these authors discuss whether Bitcoin is a bubble or not, Bouri (2017) found that Bitcoin could be used as an effective diversifier and, in some periods, also display safe-haven and hedge properties. Some studies have been dedicated to determining the factors that drive the price of Bitcoin. Bouoiyour and Selmi (2015) argue that long-term fundamentals are likely to be major contributors to Bitcoin price variations. Among others, they also found technical factors to be a positive driver of Bitcoin prices. Specifically, Georgoula (2015) and Hayes (2015) found the technical factor Hashrate to be a significant positive price driver. Bouoiyour and Selmi (2016), Garcia (2014), Kristoufek (2015) have all used Hashrate as a variable in their respective models.

Other scholars also argue for the significance of fundamental factors such as exchange-trade, equity market indices, currency exchange rates, commodity prices, and transaction volume. In contrast to Bouoiyour and Selmi (2015), Polasik (2015) states that an increase in the transaction volume will lead to higher prices and that global economic factors do not seem to be an important driver. Ciaian (2016) also found that supply and demand factors have strong impacts on price and that standard economic currency models can partly explain price fluctuations.

Kristoufek (2013, 2015) analyzed the frequency of online searches for Bitcoin, found them to be a good proxy for interest and popularity, and discovered that the relationship between the price of Bitcoin and online popularity is bidirectional. Ciaian (2016) also found a positive relationship between Wikipedia searches and Bitcoin. Others argue along the same lines as Kristoufek in that it is primarily popularity and investor attractiveness Others argue along the same lines as Kristoufek in that it is primarily popularity and investor attractiveness that drive price movements (Bouoiyour 2016).

Regarding the volatility, in order to control for homoscedasticity, we test the unconditional variance of the regression. Breaking this assumption means that the Gauss–Markov theorem does not hold and that the OLS estimators are not BLUE. Even though the unconditional variance is stable, the conditional variance may not be constant over time. Engle (1982) developed the Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity (ARCH) model that recognizes the difference between unconditional and conditional variance and lets the conditional variance change over time as a function of previous periods’ error terms. This technique has the ability to capture the effect of volatility clustering, but it requires a model with a relatively long lag structure, which makes estimation difficult. To make this task easier, Bollerslev (1986) proposed the GARCH model that enables a reduction in the number of parameters by imposing nonlinear restrictions. The GARCH model can predict unconditional variance and requires fewer parameters. In a GARCH model, the most recent observations have greater impacts on the predicted volatility.

Data Description and Potential Methodology

We have six kinds of Bitcoin data on hand. Each has different frequency and structure. First, we have daily Bitcoin data from 1 October 2013till 14 July 2021. This data has 2.843 observations. In this data set, we have open and closing price, daily high and low values. It is good to have this kind of data since it shows almost all movement of Bitcoin so far. Let’s look at the daily open price more closely and carefully. Moreover, it is useful to have these kind of variables because we can use spread values to determine future values of the price (or average daily price).

Graph 1. Historical Daily Bitcoin Prices

 

Graph 2. Historical Daily Bitcoin Returns

The first graph shows an upward trend with sharp declines and the second graph shows some kind of volatility clustering. Prices can be estimated and predicted with ARIMA type models and volatility (risk) of returns could be predicted via GARCH mechanisms.

Table 1. Summary Statistics of Daily Prices

The second type of data bulk has four data sets for the first 15 days of January 2021 depending on their recorded frequency: minute, 5-minute, 30-minute, 1 hour. Besides open, close, high, low prices it also has trading volume, which is great to have as it might be quite predictive. Below are graphs and summary statistics of those data sets. In order to save space, we only show graphs of minute data and skip the others to the appendix since they just look alike with only frequency difference. These data are important since we can predict a minute later, 5 minutes later, etc. Data sets respectively have 20.154, 4.033, 673, 337 points of observation.

Graph 3. Historical Minute Bitcoin Data

Graph 4. Historical Minute Bitcoin Returns

Table 2. Summary Statistics of Minute Prices

The last type of data are the most interesting: tick data. The data has records for each transaction occurred in milliseconds (almost all activity of Bitcoin). This data has volume and price variables and consists of 701.661 observations for just one day (4 February 2021), which is quite rich.

Graph 5. Historical Bitcoin Tick Data

Graph 6. Historical Returns of Bitcoin Tick Data

Table 3. Summary Statistics of Tick Prices

For returns of tick data, we could use more rigorous methodology rather than GARCH framework. We might try GARCH but our data is not an equidistant time-series anymore. That is why we should rather use penalized and conventional logistic models for predicting return movements. We can use more than a down-up approach and predict many categories under multinomial logistic regressions. If we have computing power and can estimate 100 categories, for example, the regression would yield a quantile prediction for a millisecond later return, which is very intriguing. One more methodology would be to find potential scaling laws in tick data as in foreign exchange or stock prices. The last two methodologies would be a great tool for algorithmic trading.

 

References:

  1. Bollerslev, Tim. 1986. Generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity. Journal of Econometrics 31: 307–27
  2. Bouoiyour, Jamal, and Refk Selmi. 2015. What Does Bitcoin Look Like? Annals of Economics and Finance 16: 449–92.
  3. Bouoiyour, Jamal, and Refk Selmi. 2016. Bitcoin: A beginning of a new phase? Economics Bulletin 36: 1430–40.
  4. Bouri, Elie, Peter Molnár, Georges Azzi, David Roubaud, and Lars Ivar Hagfors. 2017b. On the hedge and safe haven properties of Bitcoin: Is it really more than a diversifier? Finance Research Letters 20: 192–8.
  5. Cheah, Eng-Tuck, and John Fry. 2015. Speculative bubbles in Bitcoin markets? An empirical investigation into the fundamental value of Bitcoin. Economics Letters 130: 32–36.
  6. Ciaian, Pavel, Miroslava Rajcaniova, and d’Artis Kancs. The economics of BitCoin price formation. Applied Economics 48: 1799–815.
  7. Corbet, Shaen, Brian Lucey, and Larisa Yarovaya. 2017. Datestamping the Bitcoin and Ethereum bubbles. Finance Research Letters 26: 81–88.
  8. Dwyer, Gerald P. 2015. The economics of Bitcoin and similar private digital currencies. Journal of Financial Stability 17: 81–91.
  9. Engle, Robert F. 1982. Autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity with estimates of the variance of United Kingdom inflation. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 50: 987–1007.
  10. Garcia, David, Claudio J. Tessone, Pavlin Mavrodiev, and Nicolas Perony. The digital traces of bubbles: Feedback cycles between socio-economics signals in the Bitcoin economy. Journal of the Royal Society Interface 11: 1–28.
  11. Georgoula, Ifigeneia, Demitrios Pournarakis, Christos Bilanakos, Dionisios Sotiropoulos, and George M. Giaglis. 2015. Using Time-Series and Sentiment Analysis to Detect the Determinants of Bitcoin Prices. Available online: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2607167 (accessed on 10 August 2021).
  12. Hayes, Adam S. 2015. Cryptocurrency value formation: An empirical study leading to a cost of production model for valuing bitcoin. Telematics and Informatics 34: 1308–21.
  13. Hayes, Adam S. 2018. Bitcoin price and its marginal cost of production: Support for a fundamental value. Applied Economics Letters 5: 1–7.
  14. Kristoufek, Ladislav. 2015. What Are the Main Drivers of the Bitcoin Price? Evidence from Wavelet Coherence Analysis. PLoS ONE 10: e0123923.
  15. Nakamoto, Satoshi. 2008. Bitcoin: A Peer-to-Peer Electronic Cash System. Available online: http://bitcoin.org/ bitcoin.pdf (accessed on 16 August 2021).
  16. Polasik, Michal, Anna Iwona Piotrowska, Tomasz Piotr Wisniewski, Radoslaw Kotkowski, and Geoffrey Lightfoot. 2015. Price Fluctuations and the Use of Bitcoin: An Empirical Inquiry. International Journal of Electronic Commerce 20: 9–49.
  17. Yermack, David. 2013. Is Bitcoin a Real Currency? An economic appraisal. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No. 19747. Available online: http://www.nber.org/papers/w19747 (accessed on 15 August 2021).
Share article
FacebookTwitter

Facebook Comment

subscribe

BRI is a think-tank launched by independent experts aiming to provide a local and international audience with analysis, opinion and research on Azerbaijan.

bg
For the full operation of the site you need to enable JavaScript in your browser settings.